A Survey of Behavioral Finance
By: Nicholas Barberis and Richard Thaler
Barberis
and Thaler discuss the results of the behavioral finance, a fairly new field of
finance compared to the traditional finance paradigm. The key difference between behavioral finance
and the traditional finance paradigm is rationality. The traditional finance paradigm assumes
rational individuals. Rationality means
two things. First, when presented with
new information, agents update their beliefs accordingly. Second, given their beliefs, agents make
choices that are normatively acceptable.
Behavioral finance considers when some agents are not rational. Specifically, when one of the two tenets of
rationality are relaxed.
One of the
two building blocks of behavior finance is limits to arbitrage. A classic objection to behavioral finance is
that when some agents don’t act rationally, the agents who do act rationally
will prevent them from influencing prices for long due to arbitrage. A series of theoretical papers suggests
otherwise, showing that in an economy where rational and irrational investors
interact, irrationality can have a long and substantial impact on prices. This stands counter to the efficient markets
hypothesis (EMH), where put simply, the “prices are right.” Limits to arbitrage
suggest that mispricing does occur and can persist. Some reasons these limits exist are the
fundamental risks the arbitrageur faces, noise trader risks, and implementation
costs. Some evidence of the limits to
arbitrage are twin shares, index inclusions, and internet carve-outs.
The other
building block of behavior finance is psychology. The theory of limited arbitrage shows
irrational traders can cause deviations from fundamental value, but psychology seeks
to tell us why those traders act irrationally.
For guidance, economists consider extensive evidence compiled by
cognitive psychologists on the systematic biases that arise when people form
beliefs, and on people’s preferences.
Some of these beliefs that are particularly useful to behavioral finance
are overconfidence, optimism and wishful thinking, representativeness,
conservatism, belief perseverance, and anchoring. A couple things to focus on when considering
preferences are prospect theory and ambiguity aversion.
Barberis
and Thaler follow this overview by explaining some applications of behavioral finance. The first is the aggregate stock market,
where behavioral finance may help solve the equity premium puzzle and the
volatility puzzle. The second is the
cross-section of average returns.
Behavioral finance may help explain some anomalies, such as the size
premium, long-term reversals, the predictive power of scaled-price ratios,
momentum, and event studies of earnings announcements, dividend initiations and
omissions, stock repurchases, and primary and secondary offerings. The third application is closed-end funds and
comovement. The fourth is investor behavior
where irrationality and psychology can explain insufficient diversification, naïve
diversification, excessive trading, the selling decision, and the buying
decision. The last application mentioned
is corporate finance, where behavioral finance can address security issuance,
capital structure, investment, and dividends.
When De
Bondt and Thaler (1985) published their paper, many scholars felt the best explanation
was programming error. Since then, most
of the empirical facts are agreed upon but the interpretation of those facts in
still in dispute. Behavioral finance has
been very helpful in understanding possible limits of arbitrage and bounded
rationality. Barberis and Thaler concede
there are numerous degrees of freedom but note that rational modelers have just
as many options to choose from. There is
only one scientific way to compare alternative theories, behavioral or
rational, and that is with empirical tests. They say we should be skeptical of theories
based on behavior that is undocumented empirically. Barberis and Thaler conclude by giving two
predictions. First, we will find out
that most of our current theories, both rational and behavioral, are
wrong. Second, substantially better
theories will emerge.
No comments:
Post a Comment