By: John H. Cochrane
In this paper, Cochrane makes the determination that either
returns or dividend growth are forecastable.
Using this line of reasoning, he states that the absence of
predictability of one variable implies the presence of predictability in the
other variable. Cochrane works to prove
the absence or presence of dividend growth and returns here to see what can
actually be predicted and how much.
Table 1 is given at the beginning, showing some regressions that would
forecast returns and dividend growth.
In the table, real return,
real return minus real return on 3-month T-bills, and dividend growth are
forecasted using the dividend-price ratio.
Real return and real return minus real return on 3-month T-bills have a
positive and significant coefficient.
Conversely, dividend growth has a very small coefficient and is not
statistically significant. It would be
easy to simply say that this means returns can be forecasted by the
dividend-price ratio, but Cochrane says the coefficient on the return
regressions is biased upward and the t-statistic is biased toward
rejection. This means we cannot trust
the result of the returns forecasting regressions in the table. Does this mean return forecastability is
dead? No.
Looking at table one, clearly dividend growth is not
forecastable using the dividend-price ratio.
Cochrane says that “If both returns and dividend growth are
unforecastable, then present value logic implies that the price/dividend ratio
is constant, which it obviously is not.” Using this theory, it means that
either returns or dividend growth must be forecastable. Based on this logic, it leads to the simple conclusion that if dividend growth is clearly not forecastable, returns must
be forecastable despite the regressions’ bias mentioned above. Cochrane then uses different measures to
prove if dividend growth is forecastable including vector auto-regressions and
analyzing long-horizon regression coefficients.
He uses a joint distribution with a joint hypothesis/null that if
returns are forecastable then dividend growth is not and vice versa.
Vector Auto-Regressions
After going through these processes, Cochrane says there
is not a shred of evidence proving that high market price-dividend ratios are
associated with higher subsequent dividend growth. Using this result and the line of reasoning
discussed above, this means that real returns are forecastable. Cochrane notes that excess return
forecastability is not a comforting result.
Life would be easier if you could trace price movements back to visible
news about dividends or cashflows. The
evidence so far seems to be that most aggregate price/dividend variation can be
explained only by rather nebulous variation in Sharpe-ratios. Cochrane says “the only good news is that
observed return forecastability does seem to be just enough to account for the
volatility of price dividend ratios. If both return and dividend-growth
coefficients were small, we would be forced to conclude that prices follow a “bubble”
process, moving only on news (or, frankly, opinion) of their own future values.
In conclusion, setting up simple regressions for returns
and dividend growth using the dividend/price ratio to determine their
forecastability is inconclusive. Using
present value logic, we know that one of the two measures must be forecastable. This means Cochrane only has to test one
hypothesis and it will prove the other.
He chooses to prove whether dividend growth is forecastable and finds
that it is not by using measures such as basic linear regression, VARs, and
long-horizon regression estimates. This
leads to a final conclusion that returns are forecastable. A conclusion that isn’t as definitively
proven by going through the same process for returns as is done for dividend
growth.
No comments:
Post a Comment